Wednesday, July 25, 2012

QE3 Talk

There is plenty of talk, coming from Fed officials and mainstream media (NYT and WSJ, for example) that the Fed is thinking about more QE, and will announce it, either after its meeting next week, or in September.

Rightly or wrongly, the Fed has made clear how it interprets the dual mandate from Congress. The first part of the mandate, "price stability," translates to 2% inflation. The second part, "maximum employment," means concern with the labor market more generally, and often particularly with the unemployment rate. How are we doing? On the first part of the mandate, we're south of the target, as you can see in the next chart.
The chart shows the inflation rate, as measured by 12-month percentage increase in the pce deflator, and the core pce deflator. The Fed has made clear that its interest is in the raw pce inflation measure. In any case, both measures are below 2%, though not by much for the core measure. On the second part of the mandate, the recent surprises have been on the down side. Employment growth is lower than expected and the unemployment rate is not falling as expected. Nothing is settled in Europe, and fiscal policy in the United States is currently confused and confusing.

Any Taylor-rule central banker would be pushing for more monetary accommodation. But what does the Fed have available that can allow it to be more accommodating? Other than QE, here are some other possibilities:

1. Reduce the interest rate on reserves (IROR) to zero: The FOMC would announce this as a reduction in the fed funds rate target to 0%, instead of a target range of 0-0.25%, but the Board of Governors would actually have to reduce the IROR to make a difference, as it's the IROR that drives the fed funds rate under current conditions. But the Fed will not reduce the IROR to zero. Its concern is with money market mutual funds (MMMFs). With IROR at 0.25%, there seems to be enough of an interest rate differential that MMMFs can eek out a profit and retain their contracts which fix the value of a MMMF share at $1. The concern is that, if the IROR goes to zero, then there would be an exodus from MMMFs, as shareholders would fear that these MMMFs were about to "break the buck." MMMFs intermediate a lot of commercial paper, for example, so the resulting disintermediation would be "disruptive." I'm not sure that these concerns make any sense, but I'll write about that another time.

2. More forward guidance: Here's how this reads in the last FOMC statement, from June 20:
the Committee decided today to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to 1/4 percent and currently anticipates that economic conditions--including low rates of resource utilization and a subdued outlook for inflation over the medium run--are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through late 2014.
Early forward guidance language (e.g. in 2009) was more vague, mentioning only an "extended period" of low interest rates. The extended period became an explicitly specified period, and that period was lengthened to extend to late 2014. The idea behind forward guidance is that expectations about future monetary policy are important for determining the current inflation rate, for example. So monetary policy can affect inflation and perhaps real activity without the Fed actually taking any current action. All it needs to do is make commitments about future policy. Thus, the Fed could in principle be more accommodative by changing the late 2014 date to something else - maybe late 2015. The problem here is that the Fed has made clear that the "late 2014" language is something it is willing to change at will. If future events made tightening look desirable before the end of 2014 arrived, the Fed would be willing to move the date up, apparently. As a result the forward guidance language no longer has any meaning. It's not a commitment, so it's irrelevant.

So that leaves us with QE. If you have been reading these posts, you know I think QE does not matter, under current conditions. But suppose you think it does. Why would the Fed think it needs to accommodate more? It already did so at the last meeting in June, when it extended "Operation Twist" to the end of the year. Implicitly, there seems to be a view that "Operation Twist" is a milder version of QE, maybe because it does not change the size of the Fed's balance sheet. But Operation Twist and QE are actually the same thing. What matters (if you buy into QE at all) is the composition of the outstanding debt of Fed and the Treasury, and Operation Twist and QE change that composition in essentially the same way. Operation twist is a swap of short-maturity government debt for long-maturity debt, and QE is a swap of reserves for long maturity government debt (or mortgage backed securities - more about that shortly). Is there any difference between short-term government debt and reserves currently? No, not much. So Operation Twist and QE are the same thing.

But maybe the Fed thinks it was too hasty and should do more? Maybe that's what John Williams is talking about when he says there should be an
...open-ended programme of QE.
Indeed, it's always puzzled me that the FOMC has not conducted its asset purchase programs in the way it formerly targeted the fed funds rate. Why not fix the path for purchases until the next FOMC meeting, and revisit the issue at each subsequent meeting?

Here's another puzzler. The article I link to above, on John Williams, says:
If the Fed launched another round of quantitative easing, Mr Williams suggested that buying mortgage-backed securities rather than Treasuries would have a stronger effect on financial conditions. “There’s a lot more you can buy without interfering with market function and you maybe get a little more bang for the buck,” he said.
There are two claims in the quote that are worthy of note:

1. Large-scale purchases of Treasuries by the Fed could be disruptive, and large scale purchases of mortgage-backed securities are not.
2. There is a larger effect (on something) of a given purchase of assets by the Fed if the assets are mortgage-backed securities than if the assets are Treasuries.

On the first claim: I ran across a discussion of "disruption" in the minutes from the last FOMC meeting:
Some members noted the risk that continued purchases of longer-term Treasury securities could, at some point, lead to deterioration in the functioning of the Treasury securities market that could undermine the intended effects of the policy. However, members generally agreed that such risks seemed low at present, and were outweighed by the expected benefits of the action.
So what's that about? I'm not completely sure, but I think the issue is the following. People who trade in government securities seem to have a segmented view of the market for Treasuries. "On-the-run" government securities are newly-issued, and "off-the-run" are secondhand. Apparently the prices of on-the-run Treasuries tend to be higher than the prices of off-the-run Treasuries with the same duration. This difference in price is thought to be a liquidity premium, in that the market in on-the-run Treasuries is more liquid because it is thicker. To people who study market microstructure, this might make sense, but I think economists will have trouble explaining it. Why would we think of the market for Treasuries as segmented in this fashion? A secondhand Treasury is harder to price or trade than a new one? Why?

In any case, the Fed appears to do its Treasury purchases in the on-the-run market. Suppose we think that, if the Fed is more active in the market for on-the-run Treasuries, that this makes these on-the-run Treasuries hard to acquire for private sector purchasers? Why is that a problem? Isn't that the whole idea?

On the second claim above, that purchases of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) by the Fed should matter more than purchases of Treasuries, I don't see it. According to the theory the Fed seems to have in mind (to the extent it has anything on its collective mind at all) QE works because of market segmentation. You buy long-term assets and sell short-term ones, and this pushes up the price of the long-term assets, according to Ben Bernanke. But why should it make any difference whether the Fed purchases MBS or Treasuries? That would appear to be the same segment of the market. The MBS market is dominated by Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae, now government-owned enterprises. The MBS they issue are generic products, and one does not have to think much about what one is buying, just as one does not have to think much about what one is buying in the Treasury market. That's why the Fed is buying MBS and not corporate bonds. It doesn't require much thinking. More bang for the buck with MBS? I don't think so.

In my quest for actual research on why QE might matter, I ran across this paper by Mark Gertler and Peter Karadi. Here's something I like in the paper:
A popular view of LSAPs — known more broadly as "quantitative easing" — is that they reflect money creation. We instead argue that LSAPs should be seen as central bank intermediation. Just like private intermediaries the Fed has financed its asset purchases with variable interest bearing liabilities and not money per se. The difference of course is that that Fed’s liabilities are effectively government debt.
The important idea here is that it is useful to think about QE as intermediation. That's the whole key to understanding why it does or does not matter. Though Gertler and Karadi want to make a distinction between QE and conventional monetary policy or "money creation," they should think of the latter as intermediation too. The key issue is that the intermediation the Fed does will only matter and be useful to the extent that the Fed can do it better than the private sector can.

Gertler and Karadi do their best to construct a model where that is the case. There are financial frictions that gum up the private sector's ability to do something like QE. When the Fed does QE, that can be beneficial because the Fed is better at this activity than is the private sector, in the Gertler-Karadi model. It's a bit of a chicken model, and I'm not convinced, but basically they have the right idea. If you want to explain why QE matters, you have to show why the Fed is better than the private sector at turning long-term safe debt into short-term safe debt.

21 comments:

  1. re MMF disruption - presumably the fed needs the MMFs for their reverse repos when they begin to tighten, so putting them out of business now might not be the best idea?

    there seems to be plenty of evidence from japan that ZIRP has reduced private sector participation in the money market.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Why do you need a MMF to do a reverse repo?

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. I think it would be purely from an institutional point of view. I think the Fed can only conduct reverse repo's with institutions on an approved list of counterparties. Some of these CP's are MMF's. If MMF's drop in significance from withdrawals, this might impede the Fed's ability to conduct reverse repo operations to withdraw excess liquidity.

      Delete
    2. See here: http://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/rrp_counterparties.html

      Delete
    3. Yes, but all the major banks, and the GSEs are on the approved list too. You could lose all the MMFs and seemingly not put a dent in the Fed's ability to do reverse repos.

      Delete
  3. "Indeed, it's always puzzled me that the FOMC has not conducted its asset purchase programs in the way it formerly targeted the fed funds rate. Why not fix the path for purchases until the next FOMC meeting, and revisit the issue at each subsequent meeting?"

    Also, why are they specifying a quantity of purchases rather than targeting an interest rate?

    ReplyDelete
  4. Exactly. The Fed claims it can move long Treasury rates. Why not target the whole term structure if that's the case?

    ReplyDelete
  5. Stephen,

    What are the key papers on which you base your conclusion that QE cannot have any effect under current circumstances? Please let us know so that we can study these papers.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. Richard,

      All you have to do is start with the model in this paper:

      http://www.artsci.wustl.edu/~swilliam/papers/web%20page%20paper.pdf

      That's forthcoming in the AER, so it's not completely goofy. Just extend it by including bonds of different maturities, and show that, in the liquidity trap equilibria, you can do swaps across maturities and it won't matter. There are ways to be more ambitious, but that's a start. I haven't had time to write it down formally, but the reasoning is all in my blog posts.

      Delete
    2. Thanks Stephen,

      I really would like to go over that paper. Right now I'm still putting whatever time I can find into Wallace's 1981 AER. I'm trying to understand every equation, term, and sentence, seperately and in combination completely, and with the important intuitions to the real world. I'm about 70% there; it's definitely been interesting going into a very new area on my own like this with no one to ask questions (although it definitely helped that the state price paradigm is common and big in finance), a very interesting exercise.

      What I'd like to look into, too, when I'm finished going through the paper, is expanding on it by adding an error term, Eh, to the true state price vector and/or state probability vector to model heterogeneity of investor beliefs, something that obviously exists in large measure in the real world. I think if I did this I could prove that the irrelevance proposition no longer holds, and may be able to get some interesting results as to how and why.

      Delete
    3. Above I meant the true state-return-vector (X in the paper), not the state-price-vector, to add the error term to.

      Delete
  6. @ SW - the banks only have so much capacity to do reverse repos with the Fed. I would guess that capacity might be insufficient, and hence the Fed wants to be able to trade with the MMFs.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. What determines capacity? You would think that's endogenous. If the Fed starts taking their business to the banks, then capacity will increase.

      Delete
  7. "This difference in price is thought to be a liquidity premium, in that the market in on-the-run Treasuries is more liquid because it is thicker. To people who study market microstructure, this might make sense, but I think economists will have trouble explaining it. "

    There are lots of economists who have looked at this, i have texts going back 50 years.

    There are a number of things that diminish the availability of older treasuries. The supply itself of older treasuries is generally lower because of the mere fact that the national debt has a 225 year up trend. Older treasuries are often broken into strips (i.e. split into the discrete cashflows). Once broken up, hard to put back together. Bonds, once placed with buy-and-hold investors, can be difficult to pry from them (for tax or other reasons they may not want to sell). I can think of a half dozen other reasons availability of older bonds is lower.

    Conversely, Treasuries are also used for hedges (i.e. to hedge mortgages or imminent issuance). If you are using it to hedge something indexed to the ten year treasury (most contracts specifically mention the most current on-the-run) then the most efficient hedge is the exact bond the index is tied to. This phenomenon tends to create specific demand for that bond. And you only want to hedge with a bond that is easy to sell.

    Why the Fed cares is another matter. If you buy the argument that QE works by taking risk off the market onto the Feds balance sheet, that argues for buying off the runs, not on the runs, since they are riskier. Of course, it might be hard to do the size the Fed needs for the availability reasons i mentioned above...

    Oh, and i think QE will not do much good without updated guidance as well, ideally in the form of an economic target not a calendar-date.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. i forgot to mention, an important driver among those half dozen reasons i mentioned is the tax /accounting implications of premium/discount.

      for example, you can see the differential price of various treasuries on the WSJ page

      http://online.wsj.com/mdc/public/page/2_3020-treasury.html?mod=mdc_bnd_pglnk

      these three bonds nearly 10 years remaining are worth highlighting:

      maturity, coupon, bid price, ask price, chg, ask yield

      5/15/2022 1.750 103.1094 103.1719 -0.0156 1.403

      8/15/2022 7.250 155.5938 155.6406 -0.0469 1.322

      11/15/2022 7.625 160.0938 160.1875 0.0000 1.349

      The 8/15/2022 bond has a price of 155.64 because it is really old with a high coupon. the $55.64 premium over par could have some peculiar tax capital/gain loss consequences depending on the investor circumstances. Its not just that the market for off the runs is less liquid: the demand for bonds with a significant premium/discount to par makes them less liquid as well.

      Delete
  8. Even if the chicken model premise is valid, the question remains as to whether LSAP's should be carried out by the fiscal authority, not the central bank. This sis an institutional issue: contingent tax liabilities are better created through the appropriations process. The Fed's independence will be at risk if it resorts to creating contingent tax liabilities under the guise of monetary policy.

    ReplyDelete
  9. Does the Fed have any understanding that is should not do anything about inflation, if it cannot do anything about the cause of inflation?

    Specifically, I am asking about Oil, which has gone up 50 times in price, since Something Big Happened in the 1970s?

    Oil prices are frequently, if not often, driven by events external to the US economy.

    For example, the evidence is convincing to many that the 2008 crisis was caused by a one two punch: (1) rises in oil prices followed by (2) increases in interest rates. (Stock/Watson 2012)

    Said differently, has the Fed learned its lesson that, in response to oil price increases, that it should lower rates?

    Surely we can have agreement on the proposition that an oil price increase is, in economic effect, the same as a tax increase

    Prices may go up, but the effect will be deflationary.

    ReplyDelete
    Replies
    1. ironically fellas named Bernanke and Gertler wrote a paper that the recessionary impact of high oil prices was primarily due to monetary policy responses. The Fed kept rates at 2% in sept 2008 even after lehman just collapsed and business conditions were worsening, for fear of inflation due to .... high oil prices that summer. heh. the irony. ever wonder if in bernankes memoirs he'll express regret?

      Delete
  10. "To people who study market microstructure, this might make sense, but I think economists will have trouble explaining it. Why would we think of the market for Treasuries as segmented in this fashion? "

    Messrs Scholes and Merton had troubles explaining it too - one reason that LTCM went bankrupt is because they were trying to arbitrage between on-the-run and off-the-run treasuries while abstracting from the very real liquidity issues that drive the gap between these securities. That seems to symbolize how modern economists think - assume away real life details like liquidity and sticky prices because they don't fit into some idealized model. At least with Merton and Scholes, their error was revealed by the markets, but one wonders how other economists who never need submit their ideas to a true market place ever get disciplined.

    "There are financial frictions that gum up the private sector's ability to do something like QE."

    No kidding. What private institution has the muscle to precommit to $600 billion worth of asset purchases over a few quarters? Probably none. Even if there were a few that could, why would they pre-announce? No, that would amount to financial suicide.

    ReplyDelete
  11. Please do write more about #1.

    ReplyDelete